Skip to main content
Log in

Abstract

Using a simple rational choice model as a heuristic device, this paper explores the lobbying behaviour of environmental and business organisations in the field of climate policy and discusses why their lobbying behaviour differs. I find that environmental organisations lobby less than what would be considered rational according to the simple rational choice model, and argue that this might largely be explained by tight budget constraints. I also find that business organisations lobby more than what would be considered rational according to the model, and argue that this might be explained if one applies a long-term perspective on rational lobbying in the policy field rather than a short-term perspective on single policy decisions. Moreover, I find that the type of lobbying differs. While environmental organisations focus on single policy decisions, business organisations also invest in general lobbying. The analysis is based on interviews with interest organisations lobbying in the field of climate policy at the European Union (EU) level.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. A “friend” is a decision-maker who shares the interest group’s view in the matter under consideration. A “foe” is a decision-maker who does not share the interest group’s view.

  2. CO2, CH4, N2O, HFCs, PFCs, and SF6.

  3. Including the US, which has not ratified the Protocol.

  4. The 15 EU countries at the time the Kyoto Protocol was signed and ratified.

  5. The EU-15 had in 2005 reduced its emissions by 2% compared to base-year level. EEA concludes that ‘EU-15 is not on track to meet its Kyoto target, but that projections for 2010 indicate that the target will be met if Member States implement existing and additional measures fully and quickly, and make use of carbon sinks and Kyoto mechanisms’ (European Environmental Agency 2007, p. 6). However, there are large differences in targets between the member states.

  6. Business Europe from January 2007.

  7. While electricity producers benefit from the EU emissions trading system because they can pass through the costs to the consumers, the energy intensive industries oppose the existing emissions trading system—until it becomes a part of a global emissions trading system.

  8. Author’s interview with Peter Tjan, EUROPIA, Brussels, November 2005.

  9. The car industry apparently found it worth to lobby on this issue. The Commission’s proposal was postponed twice, commonly believed to be because of heavy lobbying from the German car industry. Finally, the Commission advocated an “integrated” strategy—which implied an objective of 130 grammes CO2 per kilometre by 2012 for the car industry and another 10 g/km reduction for other actors, such as tyre-makers, fuel suppliers, and drivers.

  10. Author’s interview with Nick Campbell, UNICE, Brussels, November 2005.

  11. See footnote 10.

  12. See footnote 10.

  13. This distinction corresponds with Kohler-Koch and Quittkat’s distinction between ‘regular contacts and background information’ and ‘targeted contacts and information’ (1999, p. 10).

  14. Author’s interview with Wim B. J. Philippa, ERT, Brussels, November 2005.

  15. See footnote 14.

  16. Author’s interview with Margot A. Loudon, Eurogas, Brussels, November 2005.

  17. See footnote 16.

  18. See footnote 8.

  19. See footnote 8.

  20. See footnote 8.

  21. Author’s interviews with Nick Campbell, Brussels, November 2005, Wim B. J. Philippa, ERT, Brussels, November 2005 and Peter Tjan, EUROPIA, Brussels, November 2005.

  22. Author’s interview with Mattias Duwe, CAN, Brussels, November 2005.

  23. See footnote 22.

  24. See footnote 22.

  25. See footnote 22.

  26. Author’s interview with Jeroen Verhoeven, Brussels, November 2006.

  27. See footnote 26.

  28. Author’s interview with Stephan Singer, WWF EPO, Brussels, November 2006.

  29. See footnote 28.

  30. See footnote 28.

  31. See footnote 28.

  32. Author’s interviews with Nick Campbell, UNICE, Brussels, November 2005, Wim B. J. Philippa, ERT, Brussels, November 2005 and Peter Tjan, EUROPIA, Brussels, November 2005.

  33. Author’s interviews with Dorette Corbey, MEP Socialist Group, Brussels, November 2006 and Pierre Schellekens, Cabinet of Stavros Dimas, DG Environment, Brussels, November 2006.

  34. Author’s interview with Pierre Schellekens, Cabinet of Stavros Dimas, DG Environment, Brussels, November 2006.

  35. Author’s interview with Claude Turmes, MEP Green Party, Brussels, November 2005.

  36. Author’s interviews with Mahi Sideridou, Greenpeace, Brussels, November 2005, Peter Tjan, EUROPIA, Brussels, November 2005, and Claude Turmes, MEP Green Party, Brussels, November 2005.

  37. See footnote 8.

  38. It is important to note that all motives for lobbying are strictly instrumental. One of the most common motives of non-instrumental lobbying is the interest group’s need to appear efficient in the eyes of its own members. Research on lobbying in the US finds that hearings in the Congress are an important arena for such non-instrumental lobbying (Holyoke 2003; Milbrath 1960). Lobbyists attend such hearings even though they know that the possibilities of influencing the decision-makers are limited—the latter have often made up their minds before the hearing. It is, however, ‘a useful way to the lobbyist to demonstrate to the membership that he is earning his salary’ (Milbrath 1960, p. 41).

  39. The group has become the Group of Ten, as another two organisations have joined the group.

  40. Author’s interviews with Mattias Duwe, CAN, Brussels, November 2005, Mahi Sideridou, Greenpeace, Brussels, November 2005, Stephan Singer, WWF EPO, Brussels, November 2006, and Jeroen Verhoeven, Brussels, November 2006.

  41. See footnote 22.

  42. Author’s interviews with Mattias Duwe, CAN, Brussels, November 2005, Mahi Sideridou, Greenpeace, Brussels, November 2005, and Jeroen Verhoeven, Brussels, November 2006.

  43. Author’s interview with Mattias Duwe, CAN, Brussels 2005.

  44. Author’s interviews with Nick Campbell, UNICE, Brussels, November 2005 and Wim B. J. Philippa, ERT, Brussels, November 2005.

  45. See footnote 10.

  46. See footnote 14.

  47. See footnote 10.

  48. See footnote 14.

  49. See Oliver (1993) for a review.

  50. Author’s interviews with Mattias Duwe, CAN, Brussels, November 2005 and Mahi Sideridou, Greenpeace, Brussels, November 2005.

Abbreviations

CANEurope:

Climate Action Network Europe

COP:

Conference of the Parties

DG:

Directorate-General

ECCP:

European Climate Change Programme

EP:

European Parliament

ERT:

European Roundtable of Industrialists

EU:

European Union

EU ETS:

European Emissions Trading System

Eurogas:

The European Union of Natural Gas Industry

EUROPIA:

The European Petroleum Industry Association

FoEE:

Friends of the Earth Europe

Greenpeace EU:

Greenpeace European Unit

MEP(s):

Member(s) of the European Parliament

UNFCCC:

United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change

UNICE:

Union of Industrial and Employers’ Confederations of Europe

WWF EPO:

WWF European Policy Office

References

  • Ainsworth, S. H. (1997). The role of legislators in the determination of interest group influence. Legislative Studies Quarterly, 22(4), 517–533.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Austen-Smith, D., & Wright, J. R. (1992). Competitive lobbying for a legislator’s vote. Social Choice and Welfare, 9, 229–257.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Austen-Smith, D., & Wright, J. R. (1994). Counteractive lobbying. American Journal of Political Science, 38(1), 25–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barrett, S. (2003). Environment & statecraft. The strategy of environmental treaty-making. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bauer, R. A., Pool, I. S., & Dexter, L. (1963). American business and public policy. The politics of foreign trade. New York: Atherton Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baumgartner, F. R., & Leech, B. L. (1996). The multiple ambiguities of counteractive lobbying. American Journal of Political Science, 40(2), 521–542.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beyers, J. (2004). Voice and access. Political practices of European interest associations. European Union Politics, 5(2), 211–240.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boyd, C. (2002). Lafarge and global warming. In R. Pedler (Ed.), European Union lobbying. Changes in the arena. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bouwen, P. (2002). Corporate lobbying in the European Union: The logic of access. Journal of European Public Policy, 9(3), 365–390.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bouwen, P. (2004). The logic of access to the European Parliament: Business lobbying in the committee on economic and monetary affairs. Journal of Common Market Studies, 42(3), 473–495.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Christiansen, A. C., & Wettestad, J. (2003). The EU as a frontrunner on greenhouse gas emissions trading: How did it happen and will the EU succeed? Climate Policy, 1, 3–18.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Climate Action Network. (2003). A viable global framework for preventing dangerous climate change. (CAN Discussion Paper. COP 9 Milan).

  • Climate Action Network Europe. (2007). Homepage 2007. Retrieved January 12, 2007 from http://www.climnet.org/about/directors.htm.

  • Coen, D. (2004). Environmental and business lobbying alliances in Europe: Learning from Washington? In D. Levy & P. Newell (Eds.), Business in international environmental governance: A political economy approach. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Crombez, C. (2002). Information, lobbying and the legislative process in the European Union. European Union Politics, 3(1), 7–32.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eising, R. (2007). The access of business interests to European Union institutions: Towards elite pluralism? Journal of European Public Policy, 14(3), 384–403.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elster, J. (1986). Introduction. In: J. Elster (Ed.), Rational choice. Oxford: Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Elster, J. (1989). Nuts and bolts for the social sciences. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • European Commission. (2000). The Lisbon European Council—an agenda of economic and social renewal for Europe. Contribution of the European Commission to the special European Council in Lisbon 23–24th March 2000. DOC/00/7.

  • European Council. (2000). Presidency conclusion. Lisbon European Council. 23 and 24 March 2000.

  • European Environmental Agency. (2007). Greenhouse gas emission trends and projections in Europe 2007. (EEA Report no. 5).

  • Godwin, R. K., & Seldon, B. J. (2002). What corporations really want from government. The public provision of private goods. In A. J. Cigler & B. A. Loomis (Eds.), Interest group politics. Washington DC: CQ Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Greenwood, J. (2003). Interest representation in the European Union. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grubb, M., Brack, D., & Vrolijk, C. (1999). The Kyoto protocol. A guide and assessment. London: Earthscan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gullberg, A. T. (2006). Lobbying strategies. (Paper presented at the 14. Nasjonale fagkonferansen i statsvitenskap, Bergen, Norway January 4–6).

  • Hojnacki, M. (1997). Interest groups’ decisions to join alliances or work alone. American Journal of Political Science, 41(1), 61–87.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hojnacki, M., & Kimball, D. C. (1998). Organized interests and the decision of whom to lobby in Congress. American Political Science Review, 92, 775–790.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holyoke, T. T. (2003). Choosing battlegrounds: Interest group lobbying across multiple venues. Political Research Quarterly, 56(3), 325–336.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kohler Koch, B., & Quittkat, C. (1999). Intermediation of Interests in the European Union. Working paper no. 9/1999. Mannheim: MZES.

  • Leech, B. L., & Baumgartner, F. R. (1999). Lobbying friends and foes in Washington. In A. J. Cigler & B. A. Loomis (Eds.), Interest group politics. Washington, DC: CQ Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leech, B. L., Baumgartner, F. R., Berry, J. M., Hojnacki, M., & Kimball, D. C. (2002). Organized interests and issue definition in policy debates. In A. J. Cigler & B. A. Loomis (Eds.), Interest group politics. Washington, DC: CQ Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Long, T., Salter, L., & Singer, S. (2002). WWF: European and global climate policy. In R. Pedler (Ed.), European Union lobbying. Changes in the arena. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Loomis, B. A. (2002). Interests, lobbying, and the U.S. congress. Past as prologue. In A. J. Cigler & B. A. Loomis (Eds.), Interest group politics. Washington, DC: CQ Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Markussen, P., & Svendsen, G. T. (2005). Industry lobbying and the political economy of GHG trade in the European Union. Energy Policy, 33(2), 245–255.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Matthews, D. R. (1960). U.S. senators and their world. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mazey, S., & Richardson, J. (2002). Environmental groups and the EC: Challenges and opportunities. In A. Jordan (Ed.), Environmental policy in the European Union. Actors, institutions & processes. London: Earthscan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Michaelowa, A. (1998). Impact of interest groups on EU climate policy. European Environment, 8(5), 152–160.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Michaelowa, A. (2000). The strength of different economic interests in shaping EU climate policy. Energy and Environment, 11(3), 277–292.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Milbrath, L. W. (1960). Lobbying as a communication process. The Public Opinion Quarterly, 24(1), 32–53.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oliver, P. E., & Marwell, G. (1988). The paradox of group size in collective action: A theory of the critical mass. II. American Sociological Review, 53(1), 1–8.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oliver, P. E. (1993). Formal models of collective action. Annual Review of Sociology, 19, 271–300.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Olson, M. (1971). The logic of collective action. Public goods and the theory of groups. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Olson, M. (1982). Rise and decline of nations. Economic growth, stagflation, and social rigidities. New Haven and London: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pedler, R. (2002). Introduction. In R. Pedler (Ed.), European Union lobbying. Changes in the arena. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pincione, G., & Teson, R. (2006). Rational choice and democratic deliberation: A theory of discourse failure. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Potters, J., & van Winden, F. (1992). Lobbying and asymmetric information. Public Choice, 74, 269–292.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sbragia, A. M. (2000). Environmental policy. In H. Wallace & W. Wallace (Eds.), Policy-making in the European Union. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Svendsen, G. T. (1999). U.S. interest groups prefer emission trading: A new perspective. Public Choice, 101, 109–128.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Svendsen, G. T. (2001). Designing permit trading. In C. Daubjerg & G. T. Svendsen (Eds.), Green taxation in question. Politics and economic efficiency in environmental regulation. Basingstoke: Palgrave.

    Google Scholar 

  • UNICE. (2004). Competitiveness and EU climate change policy. (Interim Report produced by COWI for UNICE).

  • UNICE. (2007). Homepage 2007. Retrieved January 12 2007, from http://www.unice.org/Content/default.asp?PageID=262.

  • Webster, R. (2000). What drives interest group collaboration at the EU level? Evidence from the European environmental interest groups. European Integration online Papers (EIoP). Retrieved March 19, 2007, from http://www.eiop.or.at.

Download references

Acknowledgements

I would like to thank three anonymous reviewers for helpful comments and Lynn P. Nygaard for comments and editorial assistance. Financial assistance by the Norwegian Research Council/SAMSTEMT/RENERGI is gratefully acknowledged.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Anne Therese Gullberg.

Appendix: Interviews

Appendix: Interviews

  • Campbell, Dr. Nick, Leader of UNICE’s climate change working group, Union des Industries de la Communauté européenne (UNICE). Brussels, 22/11/2005.

  • Corbey, Dorette, Member of the European Parliament, the Socialist Group. Brussels, 21/11/2006.

  • Duwe, Mattias, Climate Action Network Europe. Brussels, 21/11/2005.

  • Lehtonen, Terhi, Advisor, European Parliament, Group of the Greens/European Free Alliance. Brussels, 24/11/2005.

  • Loudon, Margot A., Deputy Secretary General, Eurogas. Brussels, 21/11/2005.

  • Schellekens, Pierre, Cabinet of Stavros Dimas, DG Environment. Brussels, 22/11/2006.

  • Sideridou, Mahi, EU Policy Director on Climate Change and Energy, Greenpeace. Brussels, 22/11/2005.

  • Singer, Stephan, WWF European Policy Office. Brussels, 21/11/2006.

  • Tjan, Peter, Secretary General, EUROPIA. Brussels, 18/11/2005.

  • Turmes, Claude, Member of the European Parliament, Group of the Greens/European Free Alliance. Brussles, 22/11/2005.

  • Vergote, Stephan, Directorate-General Environment. Brussels, 23/11/2005.

  • Verhoeven, Jeroen, Assistant of the climate change campaign leader, Friends of the Earth Europe. Brussels, 20/11/2006.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Gullberg, A.T. Rational lobbying and EU climate policy. Int Environ Agreements 8, 161–178 (2008). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10784-008-9067-5

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10784-008-9067-5

Keywords

Navigation